Governmental Practices
Governmental practices can of course also be trade restraining.(8) The governmental impact
can be felt through formal antitrust exemptions or parochial state action designed to promote
national champions at the expense of foreign competitors. These examples can imply the lack of
law, exceptions to law, or a lack of enforcement. Other regulatory practices such as the strategic
application of competition policy (at the expense of foreign firms and on behalf of domestic players)
can also affect on market access. Governmental practices may be overt, or they may be subtle.
Governments could be held accountable to some degree for acts of omission, such as the failure to
enforce competition laws, and the toleration of private anticompetitive conduct, such as import
cartels, as a de facto or de jure substitute for traditional protection from imports. These points are
amplified by identifying three different types of competition policy problems arising from
government actions.
The availability of governmental exemptions and exclusions from competition laws has
received extensive attention by policymakers and scholars.(9) This Advisory Committee has given
it some consideration because the effects of such practices can be felt outside the regulating
economy as well as by would-be foreign (and domestic) participants in a market. While significant
deregulation has occurred in many OECD countries, many nations have not unilaterally reviewed
and constrained the scope of their applicable exemptions and exclusions to competition policy.
Further, some exemptions may not be viewed as in an individual country's interest to repeal in that
they promote exports or have anticompetitive consequences, if any, only in offshore markets.
Individual countries may be reluctant to eliminate or reduce the scope of exemptions if its trading
partners continue to permit comparable arrangements to thrive.
A significant amount of economic activity around the world is insulated from challenge by
competition laws. One important study commissioned by the OECD (hereinafter referred to as the
1996 Hawk Report) found substantial exclusions from competition 10 OECD countries including
in employment-related activities, agriculture, energy and utilities, postal services, transport,
communications, defense, financial services, and media and publishing, among other sectors.(10)
Additional empirical work is needed to better understand the amount of economic activity affected
by such arrangements around the world.
Various groups have considered the costs and benefits of exemptions. The 1978-79 National
Commission for the Review of Antitrust Laws and Procedures undertook an extensive consideration
of antitrust immunities and economic regulation. Their report called for a broad reexamination of
antitrust immunities, affecting many sectors of the U.S. economy.(11)
The reluctance of governments to abandon their existing exemptions and exclusions is
reflected in the recent 1998 OECD Recommendation on Hardcore Cartels. That Recommendation
represented an important statement among OECD countries regarding their desire to cooperate with
enforcement actions against hardcore cartels. This constructive undertaking notwithstanding, the
Recommendation did not attempt to impose any disciplines on national exemptions and instead
acknowledges a large carve out for arrangements that "are excluded directly or indirectly from the
coverage of a Member country's own laws; or are authorized in accordance with such laws."(12)
A second problem arises from private action unleashed by government approval. The U.S.
federal analogy is the state action defense in Parker v. Brown(13) and its progeny.(14) In the United
States, actions by one state that has adverse spillovers in other states can be corrected by the political
process and the passage of federal preemptive law or other corrective measures. Internationally,
however, the problem can be more intractable. A nation may undertake measures or immunities
because it gains more from those measures than foreign parties. An additional problem with this
type of state-blessed private action is that it is regarded as state action under competition law as a
defense of the private action, but it is not typically regarded as state action in trade policy terms.
Participants at Advisory Committee hearings offered several examples of negative crossborder
spillovers from private conduct immunized by state action.(15)
A third type of problem is harm caused to outsiders by private action taken against a
background business environment of public restraints. Some of the mixed private-public restraints
discussed above can fit into this category. When most avenues for market entry are unavailable (for
example, when acquisitions are not possible or distributors are unavailable), seemingly innocuous
business practices (such as exclusive dealing contracts) may close the market to a new foreign
market entrant. Whether this last set of problems is one that should be seen as properly the concern
of competition policy or even trade policy remains controversial.